Skip to main content

Dead-On-Arrival Legislation, What Would Kant Say?

Kant

If you are a member of the legislature, state or federal, you will have discovered by now that there are inestimable benefits of introducing bills that cannot pass, the most important of which is that dead bills leave in their wake no appreciable consequences.

But dead-on-arrival bills have a useful after-life as campaign fodder. They can be used for boosting a candidate’s bona fides among narrow intersectional groups of possible voters from whom intersectional politicians hope to raise campaign cash.

In a bipartisan legislature – Connecticut has not had one for 30 years or more – dead-on-arrival bills usually originate in the House and are killed in the Senate. Of the two bodies, the Senate is often regarded as the more responsible body, brimming with realpolitikers whose eyes are sharply focused on the consequences, intended and unintended, cultural or economic, of proposed legislation.

Kant, we are told, “… is a deontologist; from the Greek, [which refers to] the science of duties. For Kant, morality is not defined by the consequences of our actions, our emotions, or an external factor. Morality is defined by duties and one’s action is moral if it is an act motivated by duty.”

Of course all politicians are motivated by what they consider to be a “duty” to hang onto their offices, and this sometimes leads them down dark byways. Generally, politicians have no moral duty to cheat their way into office or, having achieved office, to maintain their positions by proposing dead-on-arrival legislation they strongly suspect will have no consequences other than as fodder for political campaigns.

But politicians who have sworn off moral considerations rely on dead-end measures because, among other reasons, money and political prestige are rewarded in the political afterlife. U.S. Senator Chris Dodd did not become a millionaire until, having left office, he happily shouldered his duties as Chairman of Hollywood’s Motion Picture Association of America (MPAA).

“Most ways of earning money,” Henry David Thoreau reminds us, “lead downward.”

In any case, real political morality is related entirely to the LIVE political consequences of political action. All dead-on-arrival political legislation is therefore immoral by Kantian standards, because non action is unrelated to any political duty. Then too, the political duties of politicians in a democratic-republican system of government are to the whole polis, not to his own professional advancement, and the interests of the polis cannot be furthered by dead-on-arrival legislation.

In a legislature that is not bipartisan – think Connecticut – partisan legislation generally leads to unopposed LIVE consequences, often buried beneath mounds of honeyed rhetoric.

Good legislation leads to good consequences, we were taught by our Civics teachers, a long vanished species, and bad legislation leads, way down the road, to bad consequences. However, in politics, what is good for the political geese is not always immediately bad for the ganders they supposedly represent. Many legislative bills have long fuses, the unintended consequences appearing long after the legislation has been launched.

By way of example, we know that legislation leading to higher taxes and spending – the two are casually related – cannot reduce inflation, because inflation itself is a hidden tax, and the solution to high taxes (i.e. inflation) cannot be higher taxes.

 Kant would have had no difficulty faulting as “immoral” political actions that violate what he called the “categorical imperative.” We all have a moral DUTY to behave in such a way that each and every one of our actions may be considered a universal law, applicable to all mankind, including ourselves. This is why cheating and lying are inherently immoral acts. If cheating were a universal duty, everyone who cheated would in due course be cheated. If lies were tolerated in a Constitutional Republic, the representative principle would be constantly violated.

To return to dead-on-arrival legislation -- i.e. proposed legislation that cannot pass into law -- Kant might say all such legislation is immoral because a legislator has a moral duty in a Constitutional Republic to create legislation that positively benefits his or her constituents. And while dead-on-arrival legislation targeted to a narrow audience may help a legislator in his re-election campaign, dead-end legislation can never benefit the broader needs of the legislator’s constituents.

In fact, Kant might argue, it would be better for the legislator’s constituents if the legislator shirking his principzl political responsibility were to be discharged from office by a morally awake constituency that is, unlike the legislator, able to distinguish properly lies from hard truths. No sir, you may not have your cake and eat it too, however enticing the thought may be.

All politics must be moral realpolitik and not some variant of magical thinking, according to which words are totems that change reality.

You can say, until the sun goes down, that the proper definition of inflation is NOT too many dollars chasing too few goods, but saying it, as our moral philosophizing moms and dads insisted – doesn’t make it so. After all the political rhetoric is put to bed, up is still up, down is still down, twice two makes four, and moral action is inescapably related to moral duties.



Comments

Popular posts from this blog

The Blumenthal Burisma Connection

Steve Hilton , a Fox News commentator who over the weekend had connected some Burisma corruption dots, had this to say about Connecticut U.S. Senator Dick Blumenthal’s association with the tangled knot of corruption in Ukraine: “We cross-referenced the Senate co-sponsors of Ed Markey's Ukraine gas bill with the list of Democrats whom Burisma lobbyist, David Leiter, routinely gave money to and found another one -- one of the most sanctimonious of them all, actually -- Sen. Richard Blumenthal."

Powell, the JI, And Economic literacy

Powell, Pesci Substack The Journal Inquirer (JI), one of the last independent newspapers in Connecticut, is now a part of the Hearst Media chain. Hearst has been growing by leaps and bounds in the state during the last decade. At the same time, many newspapers in Connecticut have shrunk in size, the result, some people seem to think, of ad revenue smaller newspapers have lost to internet sites and a declining newspaper reading public. Surviving papers are now seeking to recover the lost revenue by erecting “pay walls.” Like most besieged businesses, newspapers also are attempting to recoup lost revenue through staff reductions, reductions in the size of the product – both candy bars and newspapers are much smaller than they had been in the past – and sell-offs to larger chains that operate according to the social Darwinian principles of monopolistic “red in tooth and claw” giant corporations. The first principle of the successful mega-firm is: Buy out your predator before he swallows

Down The Rabbit Hole, A Book Review

Down the Rabbit Hole How the Culture of Corrections Encourages Crime by Brent McCall & Michael Liebowitz Available at Amazon Price: $12.95/softcover, 337 pages   “ Down the Rabbit Hole: How the Culture of Corrections Encourages Crime ,” a penological eye-opener, is written by two Connecticut prisoners, Brent McCall and Michael Liebowitz. Their book is an analytical work, not merely a page-turner prison drama, and it provides serious answers to the question: Why is reoffending a more likely outcome than rehabilitation in the wake of a prison sentence? The multiple answers to this central question are not at all obvious. Before picking up the book, the reader would be well advised to shed his preconceptions and also slough off the highly misleading claims of prison officials concerning the efficacy of programs developed by dusty old experts who have never had an honest discussion with a real convict. Some of the experts are more convincing cons than the cons, p