Skip to main content

Waiting For Walker


Tom Foley, who according to some polls will be Governor Dannel Malloy’s likely opponent in the upcoming gubernatorial race, ran into a string of barbed wire when he made an appearance at a recent AFL-CIO gathering, a watering hole for progressives seeking political office.

Mr. Foley appeared unarmed with empty hands – largely because there is as yet no “there” in his campaign – and he was, as expected, rudely rebuffed.

To approval and titters from the floor, Lee Saunders,  president of the American Federation of State, County and Municipal Employees, warned, just before Mr. Foley stepped to the lectern, “He will tell you anything and then he will try to kill you ... We are smarter than that, aren’t we Connecticut?”


In GOP backrooms, puzzled Republicans were scratching their nobs after Mr. Foley’s appearance and asking themselves, “Why did Mr. Foley feel compelled to meet union leaders on the same common ground as, say, Mr. Malloy or Malloy gadfly Jon Pelto, who pointedly was not invited to make an appearance before the AFL-CIO crowd?” Mr. Pelto – like Mr. Malloy, a progressive, only more so -- has opened an independent campaign for governor.

The lover’s quarrel between Mr. Malloy and Mr. Pelto revolves around the question: Which of the two is a more faithful champion of union interests? Mr. Pelto thinks he is a more faithful Samuel Gompers than Mr. Malloy; Mr. Malloy, naturally, demurs. Did Mr. Foley expect to convince hard-boiled union leaders to abandon the Pelto-Malloy steamer in favor of his bark?  

Suppose, just to suppose, Mr. Foley’s view of the union incubus in Connecticut paralleled that of  Wisconsin Governor Scott Walker, the most recent bête noir of union progressives. It is not Mr. Walker’s failures that trouble union leaders but his successes: Wisconsin's Act 10, requires public employees to contribute 6 percent of their pay toward their pensions and at least 12 percent of their health plan costs; the law also repealed a so-called “fair-share requirement” that compels all public employees represented by a union to pay union fees. In the absence of the compulsory requirement, many employees have opted out of unions; in the city of Oshkosh alone, union membership has fallen from 450 to 225.



Not long ago, Mr. Walker accepted from Republicans in Connecticut its coveted Prescott Bush award, after which many Republicans in the state began to long for a “Wisconsin moment” – meaning a moment of effective resistance to public employee unions that, here in Connecticut, have been for decades the campaign love-children of progressives such as Mr. Malloy and Mr. Pelto but not, it is often forgotten, President Franklin Roosevelt, who sought to outlaw employee unions. “It is impossible,” Mr. Roosevelt insisted, “to bargain collectively with the government,” because government workers do not generate profits; they negotiate for more tax money. A union strike against taxpayers, Mr. Roosevelt said, would be “unthinkable and intolerable.”

In what sense did Mr. Foley’s implicit promises to AFL-CIO leaders clarify a winning GOP campaign message?

A winning message, some political strategists think, would be one that held together Mr. Foley’s voter base of 2010, adding to it additional votes from Republicans, independents and even some  moderate Democrats put off by the recent swing to the left of Connecticut’s new progressive hegemon. Economically, Connecticut’s new Democratic Party has turned the clock back to the rude beginnings of the Progressive Party nearly a century ago; morally, the new progressives have whizzed past both liberalism and libertarianism towards libertinism; and socially their nostrums have led to urban anarchy and illiteracy in urban public schools.

Mr. Foley need not be anti-union during his campaign, but any attempt to outbid Mr. Malloy and Mr. Pelto on issues dear to the hearts of the unions’ upper crust is doomed to fail. Republicans, Independent and even some antique Democratic moderates – most certainly over regulated businesses and much plucked Connecticut taxpayers – will respond positively to a message that cuts governmental costs by requiring unions to bear a real “shared sacrifice,” which might include increased payments to pensions, salary freezes and, somewhere down the road, an end to compulsory union fees.

Mr. Foley might easily cite Thomas Jefferson on the point. A portion of the fees collected by unions are spent agitating for policies and politicians who represent union interests, most often Democrats such as Mr. Malloy and Mr. Pelto. Those fees ought to be voluntary. Just as Mr. Roosevelt argued against public employee unions, so Mr. Jefferson argued strenuously against the tyranny of small minds: “To compel a man to furnish contributions of money for the propagation of opinions which he disbelieves and abhors, is sinful and tyrannical.”

Somehow one cannot imagine Mr. Foley unfurling that banner at a union gathering. Or this one: “If we can prevent the government from wasting the labors of the people, under the pretense of taking care of them, they must become happy." One might easily imagine the progressive head-honchoes of the Democratic Party citing that last sentiment as a justification for disinviting Mr. Jefferson to their annual Jefferson, Jackson Bailey Dinner. Perhaps they might consider extending an invitation to Mr. Foley in his stead.

Comments

peter brush said…
Let us hope for a Walker Moment with or without a Governor Foley/McKinney.
------
Next Monday’s Ruling in Harris v. Quinn
By Ed Whelan
June 27, 2014 3:32 PM

Public-sector union bosses will have difficulty sleeping this weekend, as they await the Supreme Court’s disposition on Monday of what may be the surprise blockbuster of the term, Harris v. Quinn. The Court may well overrule a dubiously reasoned precedent from 1977—Abood v. Detroit Board of Education—that held that the First Amendment allows the government to condition a person’s employment in the public sector on that person’s paying fees to a union.

Public-sector unions, of course, have benefited massively from the coerced funding that Abood allows.

Popular posts from this blog

The Blumenthal Burisma Connection

Steve Hilton , a Fox News commentator who over the weekend had connected some Burisma corruption dots, had this to say about Connecticut U.S. Senator Dick Blumenthal’s association with the tangled knot of corruption in Ukraine: “We cross-referenced the Senate co-sponsors of Ed Markey's Ukraine gas bill with the list of Democrats whom Burisma lobbyist, David Leiter, routinely gave money to and found another one -- one of the most sanctimonious of them all, actually -- Sen. Richard Blumenthal."

Powell, the JI, And Economic literacy

Powell, Pesci Substack The Journal Inquirer (JI), one of the last independent newspapers in Connecticut, is now a part of the Hearst Media chain. Hearst has been growing by leaps and bounds in the state during the last decade. At the same time, many newspapers in Connecticut have shrunk in size, the result, some people seem to think, of ad revenue smaller newspapers have lost to internet sites and a declining newspaper reading public. Surviving papers are now seeking to recover the lost revenue by erecting “pay walls.” Like most besieged businesses, newspapers also are attempting to recoup lost revenue through staff reductions, reductions in the size of the product – both candy bars and newspapers are much smaller than they had been in the past – and sell-offs to larger chains that operate according to the social Darwinian principles of monopolistic “red in tooth and claw” giant corporations. The first principle of the successful mega-firm is: Buy out your predator before he swallows

Down The Rabbit Hole, A Book Review

Down the Rabbit Hole How the Culture of Corrections Encourages Crime by Brent McCall & Michael Liebowitz Available at Amazon Price: $12.95/softcover, 337 pages   “ Down the Rabbit Hole: How the Culture of Corrections Encourages Crime ,” a penological eye-opener, is written by two Connecticut prisoners, Brent McCall and Michael Liebowitz. Their book is an analytical work, not merely a page-turner prison drama, and it provides serious answers to the question: Why is reoffending a more likely outcome than rehabilitation in the wake of a prison sentence? The multiple answers to this central question are not at all obvious. Before picking up the book, the reader would be well advised to shed his preconceptions and also slough off the highly misleading claims of prison officials concerning the efficacy of programs developed by dusty old experts who have never had an honest discussion with a real convict. Some of the experts are more convincing cons than the cons, p